About us

The de Borda Institute

aims to promote the use of inclusive, multi-optional and preferential voting procedures, both in parliaments/congresses and in referendums, on all contentious questions of social choice.

This applies specifically to decision-making, be it for the electorate in regional/national polls, for their elected representatives in councils and parliaments, for members of a local community group, a company board, a co-operative, and so on.  But we also cover elections.

               * * * * *

The Institute is named after Jean-Charles de Borda, and hence the well-known voting procedure, the Borda Count BC; but Jean-Charles actually invented what is now called the Modified Borda Count, MBC - the difference is subtle:

In a vote on n options, the voter may cast m preferences; and, of course, m < n.

In a BC, points are awarded to (1st, 2nd ... last) preferences cast according to the rule (n, n-1 ... 1) {or (n-1, n-2 ... 0)} whereas,

in an MBC, points are awarded to (1st, 2nd ... lastpreferences cast according to the rule (m, m-1 ... 1).

The difference can be huge, especially when the topic is controversial: the BC benefits those who cast only a 1st preference; the MBC encourages the consensual, those who submit not only a 1st preference but also their 2nd (and subsequent) compromise option(s) And if (nearly) every voter states their compromise option(s), an MBC can identify the collective compromise.

 _/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-

DECISION-MAKER
Inclusive voting app 

https://debordavote.com

THE APP TO BEAT ALL APPS, APPSOLUTELY!

(The latest in a long-line of electronic voting for decision-making; our first was in 1991.)

 _/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-

FINANCES

The Institute was estabished in 1997 with a cash grant of £3,000 from the Joseph Rowntree Charitabe Trust, and has received the occasional sum from Northern Ireland's Community Relations Council and others.  Today it relies on voluntary donations and the voluntary work of its board, while most running expenses are paid by the director. 

 _/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-

A BLOG 

"De Borda abroad." From Belfast to Beijing and beyond... and back. Starting in Vienna with the Sept 2017 TEDx talk, I give lectures in Belgrade, Sarajevo, Istanbul, Tbilisi, Yerevan, Tehran, Beijing, Tianjin, Xuzhou, Hong Kong and Taiwan... but not in Pyongyang. Then back via Mongolia (where I had been an election observer in June 2017) and Moscow (where I'd worked in the '80s).

I have my little fold-up Brompton with me - surely the best way of exploring any new city! So I prefer to go by train, boat or bus, and then cycle wherever in each new venue; and all with just one plastic water bottle... or that was the intention!

The story is here.

In Sept 2019, I set off again, to promote the book of the journey.  After the ninth book launch in Taipei University, I went to stay with friends in a little village in Gansu for the Chinese New Year.  The rat.  Then came the virus, lockdown... and I was stuck.

_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-

The Hospital for Incurable Protestants

The Mémoire of a Collapsed Catholic

 This is the story of a pacifist in a conflict zone, in Northern Ireland and the Balkans.  Only in e-format, but only £5.15.  Available from Amazon.

 

_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/-_/- 

 

The director alongside the statue of Jean-Charles de Borda, capitaine et savant, in l’École Navale in Brest, 24.9.2010. Photo by Gwenaelle Bichelot. 

Search
Login
Powered by Squarespace
Won by One
WELCOME

Welcome to the home page of the de Borda Institute, a Northern Ireland-based international organisation (an NGO) which aims to promote the use of inclusive voting procedures on all contentious questions of social choice. For more information use the menu options above or feel free to contact the organisation's headquarters. If you want to check the meaning of any of the terms used, then by all means have a look at this glossary.

As shown in these attachments, there are many voting procedures for use in decision-making and even more electoral systems.  This is because, in decision-making, there is usually only one outcome - a singe decision or a shopping ist, a prioritisation; but with some electoral systems, and definitely in any proportional ones, there can be several winners.  Sometimes, for any one voters' profile - that is, the set of all their preferences - the outcome of any count may well depend on the voting procedure used.  In this very simple example of a few voters voting on just four options, and in these two hypothetical examples on five, (word document) or (Power-point) in which a few cast their preferences on five options, the profiles are analysed according to different methodologies, and the winner could be any one of all the options.  Yet all of these methodologies are called democratic!  Extraordinary!

« 2020-05 Majority Voting...Catalyst of Populism | Main | 2020-03 Taiwan Election Observation Mission »
Sunday
Jan192020

2020-04 Taiwan: everyone's electoral system?

TAIWAN ELECTIONS, 11.01.2020      OBSERVATION REPORT, SUPPLEMENT

THE DE BORDA INSTITUTE                 www.deborda.org

1          A Voters’ Profile 

Comparing the accuracy of different decision-making systems – from binary voting to preferential – is relatively easy.  Because of PR, however,[1] electoral systems vary enormously, and there are over 300 of them.  Suffice at this stage to say that, for any one electorate at any one time with any one set of preferences, a change in the electoral system might cause a huge difference in the results.

Consider, then, a democratic nation of just 240 voters: 12 little villages of 20 voters each, preparing to elect a parliament of 12 members: a simple setting which translate easily into a Taiwanese scenario.  And let it be assumed (a) that society is very homogenous – there are no ghettoes, rich suburbs, sectarian enclaves or other partisan concentrations of voters – and (b) that every village is the same, politically: 20 voters with 1st preferences for the various parties/candidates – A, B, C and D – as shown in Table I. 

Table I           10  voters’ 1st preferences 

 

Number of voters

8

3

4

5

1st preference

A

B

C

D

 

For those who believe that politics should be majoritarian, there is no majority in favour of any one party, so the corollary is also true: there is a majority against every party.  An accurate assessment of the voters’ collective will is therefore more likely to be achieved by an analysis of the voters’ preferences.  A full set is assumed to be as shown in Table II.

Table II          10  voters’ profile 

 

Preferences

Number of voters

8

3

4

5

1st preference

A

B

C

D

2nd preference

B

C

B

B

3rd preference

C

D

D

C

4th preference

D

A

A

A

 

On the face of it, opinions on party/candidate A are very divided; those on D are rather less polarised; party/candidate C enjoys some overall support but, with a 1st or 2nd preference from every voter, B is obviously the most popular.  So with 12 MPs to be elected, maybe the fairest result would be 4 B, 4 C, 2 D and 2 A, or perhaps 4 B, 3 C, 3 D and 2 A.  But what happens in practice when different electoral systems are employed?   

2          The Setting

Non-PR systems take place in single-seat constituencies.  With PR, the minimum constituency size is normally taken to be a 3-seater.  This paper will examine various electoral systems in one 12-seater, two 6-seater and/or three 4-seater constituencies, as appropriate.  The analyses for each of several electoral systems in this hypothetical democracy of 240 voters are shown in Table III.

Taiwan’s parliamentary elections relate to 73 MPs under first-past-the-post, FPTP, and about half that number, 34, under a closed PR-list system with the Hare quota; in the following analysis, Taiwan’s numbers of 8 and 4 mps are therefore considered to be an accurate reflection.  Germany’s system is half-and-half – half FPTP and half PR-list – so this means 6 MPs would be elected under FPTP, and 6 with a PR-list system under d’Hondt.  Slovenia’s BC elections apply only to her ethnic minorities and is here analysed in three 4-seaters, while Denmark uses open PR-list to elect 175 MPs in 10 constituencies, so this best translates as one constituency of 12 MPs. 

3          The Analyses

It must be emphasised that the following results for the first three systems listed – FPTP, TRS and AV, the two-round system and the alternative vote – would apply only if society was, yes, homogenous, socially, economically, religiously, ethnically, but not necessarily politically.  Nevertheless, at least in this setting, FPTP, TRS and AV are all hopelessly inaccurate; single preference PR-list systems are also not the best, especially if conducted in relatively small constituencies, as in Taiwan, rather than a large one, as in Denmark, but this too is biased.  Taiwan’s semi-PR electoral system, in which such a major component is FPTP, is also liable to produce fake results; Germany’s all-PR system of MMP, multi-member proportional, is much better, because the A party, having gained so many seats in the FPTP part, doesn’t get any more in this analysis from the second part, the PR half. 

The BC is not PR, and nor for that matter is the more inclusive MBC; hence, of course, the introduction of the quota into the quota Borda system, QBS.  In a straight contest, therefore, if the Slovenian BC system were used, party A could nominate three x 4 = 12 candidates – A1 + A2 + A3 + A4, etc. – and thus win all three x 4 seats.

Ireland, South and North, uses PR-STV.  Southern Ireland is best compared in three 4-seater constituencies, the North to two 6-seaters.  In days gone by, some very large constituencies were quite common, but the counts therein were often pretty complicated, and the maximum in current usage is a 6-seater.  In the 4-seater analysis, A and B are elected on merit, C and D by default; in the 6-seater, A, B, C and D all get a quota of 1st preferences, A actually gets two of them, and D gets a second success by default: so the final result is 2 A, 2 D, 1 B, 1 C. 

Table III        The Election Results

 

Electoral

System

 

Used in?

 

PR

or?

The

constituencies

 

Scores per

constituency

 

Results: MPs elected to parliament.

Number of MPs of which party…

No of?

No of voters

in each?

No of MPs

in each?

 

… in the single constituency

 

… overall

FPTP

uk

x

12

20

1

A-8. D-5, C-4, B-3

A

12 A

TRS

France

x

12

20

1

D-12, A-8

D

12 D

AV

Australia

x

12

20

1

C-12, A-8

C

12 C

Par-

allel

FPTP

 

Taiwan

 

semi

 8

20

1

A-8. D-5, C-4, B-3

8 A

 

9 A 1 D 1 C + 1 A/B*

PR

1

240

4

1 A 1 D 1 C + 1 A/B*

 

MMP

FPTP

 

Germany

 

6

40

1

A-8. D-5, C-4, B-3

6 A

 

6 A 2 D 2 C 2 B

PR

1

240

6

3 A 1 D 1 C 1 B

 

BC

 

Slovenia

 

x

 

3

 

80

 

4

At

best:

 

4 x (B-63, C-51, A-44, D-42)

 

3 B + 3 C + 3 A + 3 D

At worst:

 

4 x (A1 + A2 + A3 + A4 ) = 4 A

 

12 A

PR-list

Denmark

1

240

12

5 A + 3 D + 2 C + 2 B

 

PR-STV

 

Ireland

 

3

80: q = 21

4

1 A + 1 B + 1 C + 1 D

3 A + 3 B + 3 C + 3 D

2

120: q = 18

6

2 A + 2 D + 1 B + 1 C

4 A + 4 D + 2 B + 2 C

 

QBS

 

 

3

80: q = 21

4

1 A + 1 B + 1 C + 1 D

3 A + 3 B + 3 D + 3 C

2

120: q = 18

6

2 B + 2 C + 1 D + 1 A

4 B + 4 C + 2 D + 2 A

                     

 

*          Parties A and B tie for the fourth seat.   q = quota

4          Conclusion

It is quite possible that despite the dominance of FPTP which can be so hopelessly inaccurate, the results of the recent Taiwanese elections would not have been very different from those declared on election day.  In the UK, however, if PR-STV or any other form of PR had been the norm, the results would have been very very different: with nearly 1 million votes, the Green Party won 1 seat; with 17 times as many votes, the Tory party won not 17 times but 365 times as many seats!  That’s outrageous, you might think.  Indeed, the choice of electoral system is often outrageous: parties invariably choose that which is in their vested interest.  Sadly, human rights lawyers and others rarely compare the various methodologies’ democratic credentials and/or their relative merits, and as stated in the main report, nor too do most international election observation missions.

In the above comparison at least, when compared on a scale of accuracy, the top electoral system is QBS, ideally, in six-seater constituencies.  Next comes PR-STV, then, maybe, a BC.  After that it’s Denmark’s, Germany’s and Taiwan’s systems, in that order.  The rest, as stated, are just hopelessly inaccurate.

5          Recommendation

That Taiwan gives consideration to the introduction of an electoral system which is both preferential and proportional.  The use of a non-binary and therefore multi-optional form of parliamentary decision-making might also help to create that which could serve as a brilliant example of an inclusive democracy, not least to its nearest neighbour.

 

Peter Emerson

Director, the de Borda Institute

Belfast BT14 7QQ

Northern Ireland

www.deborda.org

 

2020.01.19      Liaocheng, China.

 

Abbreviations

 

AV*      =          alternative vote             BC =          Borda count                 FPTP =          first-past-the-post

IRV*     =          instant run-off voting    MBC =          modified BC MMP =          multi-member proportional

PR =          proportional representation    PV*      =     preference voting     QBS =          quota Borda system               

STV *     =          single transferable vote    TRS =          two-round system

 

*          Four different names for the same system.  When used in single-seat constituencies, it is normally referred to as AV; in multi-member constituencies with PR, the system is called PR-STV; IRV is the American term; while in Australasia it is called PV, preference voting.

 


[1]           Invariably in decision-making, the final outcome can be only a sole decision, or just one prioritisation, or whatever, but always a singleton.  In contrast, when electing representatives, there may be just the one winner in a presidential contest or in a single-seat constituency in a parliamentary election, or there may be quite a few in a multi-member constituency, as in Ireland’s three- or four-seaters, or well over a hundred when the entire country is just the one constituency, as is the Dutch system. 

PrintView Printer Friendly Version

EmailEmail Article to Friend